Natural resources and the South China Sea. Yesterday,
we introduced the way in which natural resources may be distributed, and the
fact that there are other elements for consideration (for example, exploration
and exploitation). How can this work here?
In the case of the South China Sea, the many parties
(China, the Philippines, Taiwan, Vietnam, Brunei, Malaysia, Thailand,
Indonesia, Cambodia) could be co-owners of the natural resources located in the
territorial sea and the exclusive economic zone. Undoubtedly, there are several
differences amongst China, the Philippines, Taiwan, Vietnam, Brunei, Malaysia,
Thailand, Indonesia, Cambodia. Therein, some of these differences show how the
EGALITARIAN SHARED SOVEREIGNTY could work.
The first difference is given by the fact the islanders
possess the total of natural resources at stake (100%). By applying the
egalitarian shared sovereignty, each party receives the rights to the same
ideal portion (an equal percentage of the ownership of natural resources, minus
original ownership of the inhabitants of the islands in question). It would be
either over simplistic or naïve to imagine China, the Philippines, Taiwan,
Vietnam, Brunei, Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia, Cambodia be able to explore and
exploit to the same level their shares of natural resources (second
difference). However, each of them individually have some elements that put
them in a better position in relation to the rest, for example local work
force, geographical proximity (third difference).
With all these differences in mind, the could explore
and exploit natural resources (as they are the party most developed technically
and economically to do it), and both the islanders and territories adjacent to
areas rich in natural resources could offer the work force for the joint venture
and grant privileges in terms of location to Chinese and Taiwanese companies.
Thus, less advantaged parties in terms of means for exploration and
exploitation could also offer China certain exclusive rights in the sea-zone that
overlaps with their jurisdictions.
Continuous assistance from China to other parties might
become a permanent feature (it may lead to domination or an unbalanced
relationship). To avoid this, China
would have to help the others in developing their means of exploration and exploitation
to relatively the same level they have.
At the beginning of the agreement China indeed would
be contributing more towards the exploration and exploitation and hence have a
larger return. However, these uneven distributions of burdens and benefits
amongst the parties would only be in the short term. Natural resources and all
that they imply in terms of rights and obligations are part of a wider
agreement that has a target: the South China Sea.
Finally, the way in which each party redistributes the
benefits of this shared model within each population is entirely a matter of
national or local distribution and hence may have various forms. That is to
say, the egalitarian shared sovereignty gives the basic structure of the solution;
the details are subject to actual rather than hypothetical negotiation. As an
example only, the resultant revenues of some or all the joint activities could
be destined to a distribution fund.
NOTE: based on Chapter 7, Núñez, Jorge Emilio. 2017. Sovereignty Conflicts and
International Law and Politics: A Distributive Justice Issue. London and New
York: Routledge, Taylor and Francis Group.
Jorge Emilio Núñez
Twitter:
@London1701
28th September 2018
No comments:
Post a Comment